My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
4.4. SR 11-08-2004
ElkRiver
>
City Government
>
City Council
>
Council Agenda Packets
>
2000 - 2010
>
2004
>
11/08/2004
>
4.4. SR 11-08-2004
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
1/21/2008 8:33:59 AM
Creation date
11/5/2004 7:57:16 AM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
City Government
type
SR
date
11/8/2004
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
50
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
View images
View plain text
<br />Purchase of Development Rights, CDFS-1263-98 <br /> <br />Page 2 of5 <br /> <br />guarantee is achieved to ensure that the parcel will remain agricultural, or as open (green) space forever. <br />This is because the agency involved retires the development rights upon purchase. The deed restriction <br />may also be referred to as a conservation easement, or, since most PDR programs are designed to <br />preserve agricultural use, an agricultural conservation easement (see OSU Extension Fact Sheet CDFS <br />1261-98, Conservation Easements). As a result, PDR programs are occasionally called PACE programs <br />(purchase of agricultural conservation easements). <br /> <br />How is the price of the development right determined? <br /> <br />The principal reason that more and more farmland and open space has been converted to other uses is <br />because in most areas at the rural urban fringe, the current agricultural value associated with land is <br />substantially lower than the value that land has for development. For example, consider a piece of land <br />that generates a net income of $1 00 per acre per year in agriculture. This amount is typical of much <br />farmland in the U.S. To obtain a fair market value for that parcel in agriculture, we simply divide that <br />annual income flow by the interest rate, say 5%. This procedure, called income capitalization, yields a <br />value of $2,000 per acre in this example. Now suppose that this parcel comes under development <br />pressure as a place to build housing or some type of retail establishment A developer may be willing to <br />pay $5,000 an acre for it. In this case the development value of the parcel would be $3,000 per acre, <br />simply the difference between the overall market value and the agricultural value. With this type of <br />differential, it is very unlikely that the parcel will remain in agriculture in the future, even if the current <br />owner is dedicated to keeping the land as it is. <br /> <br />If the local agency in charge of operating the PDR program makes an offer of $3,000 an acre to the <br />landowner, then that landowner has the opportunity to realize the economic benefits accrued ftom the <br />development potential of the land., while having the ability to keep the land as agricultural. At any time <br />after selling the development rights, the landowner may sell the property itself, lease it, or pass it on to <br />heirs with the deed restriction attached. <br /> <br />This is a significant change ftom the situation that farmers usually face as being "cash poor - land rich" <br />and limited to the option of selling the land for development versus owning a very valuable piece of <br />property while realizing none of the fmancial benefits. <br /> <br />Why should a community consider farmland preservation programs? <br /> <br />If, as stated above, it is primarily market forces which are driving land out of agricultural and open space <br />uses, then it is only natural to ask, why interfere with this process? Ifland achieves its "highest and best <br />use" only when developed., should this not be allowed to happen? Why not allow the ftee market in real <br />estate to determine land use? <br /> <br />Studies have shown that many U.S. citizens are deeply concerned about the loss offarmland and open <br />space. Many are concerned that increasing urban and suburban encroachment will lead to a host of <br />environmental problems, ranging ftom loss of wildlife habitat to a decline in water quality. Also, many <br />people enjoy the aesthetic beauty and sense of place that rural landscapes provide. The provision of <br />environmental and aesthetic amenities is typically not incorporated into the values of private markets. <br />There is simply no way that most landowners can achieve fmancial rewards for providing these types of <br />"public goods." Finally, some Americans are concerned that the nation's future capacity to produce its <br />own food and fiber, and thus national security, will be compromised if the trends in loss of farmland and <br />open space are not slowed down or stopped. <br /> <br />There are other economic arguments for farmland protection programs. An enormous amount of <br /> <br />http://ohioline.osu.edulcd-fact/1263.html <br /> <br />11/2/2004 <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.